Tuesday, Jun. 21, 2005

Sorry, Your Policy Is Canceled

By GEORGE J. CHURCH

On the Hawaiian island of Molokai, pregnant women who want a doctor in attendance when they give birth fly to neighboring Oahu or Maui. The five Molokai doctors who once delivered babies have stopped doing so because malpractice insurance would cost them more than the total of any obstetrical fees they could hope to collect.

Will County, Ill., last week closed its forest preserves until it can get a new liability policy on them--if that can be done at all--and Blue Lake, Calif. (pop. 1,200), has shut its skating rink, parks and tennis court. Hundreds of other towns in California and in New York State are "going bare." That is, they simply cannot get liability insurance.

The Texas sesquicentennial cattle drive, part of the state's celebration of 150 years of independence from Mexico, bogged down this month after one day on the road because liability insurance covering the 49 longhorn steers that were involved was doubled and the organizers could not afford it. The drive resumed last Friday with only 28 steers, whose owners agreed to pay for the insurance themselves.

Century Cartage Co., a small truck line out of Atlanta, is still in business only because the Georgia Public Service Commission approved an "emergency" 5% rate increase for its customers. But that boost came nowhere near meeting the cost of liability-insurance premiums that doubled to $48,000 last year and then leaped to $114,000 at the start of 1986.

Outrageous? Yes. Ridiculous? In many cases. Unreasonable? Certainly. And yet the examples represent just a small sampling from a rising flood of problems growing out of what has become a new national crisis. Given the litigious nature of American society these days, just about any kind of business, profession or government agency is likely to become the target of a suit alleging malpractice or negligence resulting in personal injury. That makes liability insurance, the kind that pays off on such claims, just about as vital as oil in keeping the economy functioning. But in the past two years, liability insurance has become the kind of resource that oil was in the 1970s: prohibitively expensive, when it can be bought at all. The result is a pinch from which few can escape--not even liability specialists like J.B. Spence or Robert Rearden.

Spence, a Miami lawyer, is the kind of attorney insurers often blame for their troubles. He has won and earned a healthy slice of several multimillion-dollar awards for clients who suffered personal injuries. But if Spence should be sued for malpractice or negligence, as is happening to lawyers more and more, he would have to pay any court-ordered damages out of his own pocket. "There is no market that will sell me liability insurance," says Spence. "I am going bare, and it is a frightening prospect."

Rearden, president of Duncan Peek Inc., an Atlanta insurance brokerage, earns commissions selling policies at soaring premium rates. But when the time came to renew his own professional liability policy, his carrier wanted to jack up his $13,000 premium by 861%, to $125,000; Rearden had to scramble to find another company that would only triple his premium cost. "And that's me, and I'm in the insurance business!" wails Rearden. "That's what I mean when I say this crisis is affecting everybody."

And how. After years of eye-popping damage awards and shortsighted insurance-company practices, the U.S. is in danger of having its insurance canceled. The cost of this crisis, once generally hidden, is now hitting home. The $9.1 billion Americans paid last year in liability-insurance premiums was almost 60% higher than the figure as recently as 1983 and roughly equal to the combined 1985 budgets of the National Aeronautics and Space Administration and the Central Intelligence Agency. This year's total is sure to show another giant leap.

Every American pays: doctors and their patients, ski-slope operators and their patrons, municipal governments and their taxpayers, those who process cheese and those who eat pizza, those who take the bus and those who lease private jets, those who drill for oil and those who heat their homes.

Even more insidiously, the problem threatens the very character of American life, from the Great Peace March across the U.S. (which came apart last week in the Mojave Desert, partly because of a lack of liability coverage) to police patrols in New York's suburban Rockland County (suspended last week in the towns of Piermont and Sloatsburg; 13 officers have been told to sit at headquarters' desks while the towns look for a liability insurer to replace one that has gone into receivership). Factory owners seeking to expand, entrepreneurs seeking to launch new enterprises, young businessmen seeking to set up shop: all are running into an obstacle far harder to surmount than high taxes and interest rates in their pursuit of the American dream. Liability insurance has become their most crippling cost.

As a result, doctors have been marching on state capitols, some threatening to shut down their practices. Industry groups and insurance companies have launched loud lobbying and advertising campaigns. Bills have been introduced or passed in all 50 state legislatures to limit liability awards or regulate insurance practices or both. Congress has held public hearings. But federal and state lawmakers, who have been faced with cutting through a jungle of conflicting statistics, arcane accounting practices and tangled legal theory, have mostly come out baffled. Says South Dakota Republican Senator Larry Pressler: "We have not been able to get past the finger-pointing stage."

Consumer groups point to the insurance companies. When interest rates were high, they say, insurers wrote policies with little concern about how they would make good if claims went up and returns on their investments went down. Insurers point to the legal system. Juries, they say, have been handing out punitive damage awards that resemble lottery jackpots. Lawyers point to the negligence of Big Business. It can be redressed, they say, only if individuals have a right to present their cases to a jury. Businessmen point to changing attitudes. The individualistic notion of taking risks and accepting responsibility, they say, has been replaced by a sue-everyone-in-sight reaction to any accident. What makes the problem such a nightmare is that, to some extent, all of the finger pointers have a point.

What it finally boils down to is a matter of statistical logic and insurer psychology. If a few giant jury awards, actual or merely possible, can offset the premiums on an entire line of insurance, the companies feel they must raise premiums for everybody until there is some hope of making a profit. This means that premiums may bear no relationship to an individual policyholder's record, and buyers of many kinds of insurance are suddenly paying three or four times as much as they did a year or so earlier. Of all places, Hartford, Conn., known as the insurance capital of the world because so many carriers have their headquarters there, saw its own municipal liability coverage slashed to only $4 million, vs. $31 million in the 1984-85 fiscal year, despite a 20% rise in total premiums, to $1.8 million.

Some insurers are shying away from covering certain types of risks at any price. If there is no way of figuring what kind of damages a jury might award to the parents of a child molested at a day-care center, for example, then the companies will find it best to stop writing that kind of insurance at all. Says James Wood, a member of a firm of actuaries whose headquarters are in Atlanta: "If you are an insurer and have $100,000 in assets, do you want to risk those assets to keep day-care centers open? The answer is probably no, because you do not know what you have to charge when you do not know what the ultimate costs of providing coverage might be." Most insurers flatly refuse to write policies to protect companies against suits arising from injuries caused by environmental pollution. They say they have no way of gauging the risk. That complicates further the question of who will pay for cleaning up toxic-waste dumps.

The dubious distinction of paying the highest increase on record may belong to Specialty Systems Inc., a Richmond, Ind., company that specializes in removing asbestos from buildings. Insurers are so terrified of anything having to do with asbestos that they canceled Specialty's policies three times between November 1984 and last April, though the nine-year-old company has never been sued. Because customers demand proof of insurance before they will give Specialty any business, the company wound up buying a $500,000 policy from the Great American Insurance Co. of Cincinnati, on which it will pay at least $460,000 in premiums, an increase of more than 4,900% over the $9,361 premium on its last fullyear policy. Says Specialty President Frederick Treadway: "About half a million dollars paid to the insurance company for virtually nothing."

The situation is studded with an endless variety of similar horror stories (see boxes). Among the most prominent are those that involve municipal services. The city council of Blue Island, Ill. (pop. 22,000), last October voted down a 30% increase in property taxes thought necessary to pay rocketing liability-insurance premiums, and the town expects to self-insure for the 1986-87 fiscal year, taking a chance that a large judgment might force taxes up anyway. Five counties in Missouri closed their jails for several weeks last fall, sending some prisoners elsewhere for incarceration and releasing minor offenders outright. The jails reopened after the counties' sheriffs set up a self-insurance pool, which was financed by tax money.

Among professionals, malpractice insurance problems have plagued lawyers, engineers, members of corporate boards and even clergymen. A growing number of clerics are buying, or having their churches buy, policies to protect them against suits like the one brought by a California couple who attributed the suicide of their 24-year-old son largely to inept counseling by his pastors. (That particular suit, filed in 1980, was dismissed for a second time last year; the case is still being appealed.) Suits against doctors, particularly specialists such as obstetricians and neurosurgeons, have been more successful and have led to some of the highest insurance premiums. A typical annual premium for an obstetrician in Los Angeles is about $45,000, and for a neurosurgeon in Long Island, N.Y., about $83,000.

Product-liability insurance presents a major problem for the makers of everything from toys to antitoxins. Pertussis vaccine for children ran short a year ago because Connaught Laboratories suspended production for a nine-month period during which it could not find insurance at an acceptable price. Now Lederle Laboratories, the only other maker of the vaccine, is talking of halting output in July if a threatened cutoff of its liability insurance materializes. Beech Aircraft figures the cost of liability premiums at a stunning $80,000 on each plane it sells. Says William Mellon, director of corporate communications: "The owner-pilot market has all but dried up, and one cause is the cost of product liability. It has driven the price of a new airplane out of the reach of the average person who wants to buy one." Some commercial fishing boats that once sailed out of Pacific Northwestern ports have been put into dry dock because owners could not afford liability-insurance premiums that commonly have doubled in the past year or so.

Rising premiums are forcing up prices on a variety of services too. Ski-lift tickets are jumping by $2 or $3 at many resorts. Through last year Kennestone Hospital in Marietta, Ga., insured itself for the first $1 million of any claims that might be made and paid a premium of $70,000 for additional coverage up to a maximum of $10 million. Now the premium has quintupled to $350,000, and on top of that the hospital has had to come up with another $1 million for its self-insurance trust fund, because the deductible was raised to $2 million. Says Executive Director Bernard Brown: "If you come to our hospital, you pay the price. It is being passed through."

Day-care centers, which have become an essential part of American life in an era of two-career families, are a striking example of how the insurance crunch may soon affect the lives of many unwary citizens. Operators fume that allegations of child abuse at a handful of centers have spooked insurers into indiscriminately canceling liability policies or demanding giant premiums. Mission Insurance Group, the chief provider of coverage for day-care centers, abruptly pulled out of the business last year. The handful of insurers that will still write day-care policies insist either on specifically excluding claims for damages arising from sexual abuse or setting up rules for strict supervision, such as unannounced visits by special investigators. Says Suzanne Grace, associate director of the Georgia Day Care Association: "The insurers are telling us, 'We don't care what your record is.' This business has the perceived risk of killing an insurance company."

There is one area of general agreement about what has caused the insurance crisis: plain old-fashioned greed. Ah, but whose greed?

Insurers and some of their customers blame aggressive lawyers, inventive judges and soft-hearted juries for twisting legal concepts of negligence into novel shapes to justify excessive damage awards to people who claim personal injury (a tort in legal parlance). Avaricious lawyers, they argue, seek outrageously high damages for clients who have flimsy cases, so that the lawyers can reap huge contingency fees (if the case fails the plaintiff's attorney earns nothing, but if it succeeds he commonly takes one-third and, on occasion, as much as 50% of the award). Says Edward Levy, general manager of the Association of California Insurance Companies: "Lawyers are out to make a buck, and they seem to have little concern for the overall societal effects of what they are doing."

Plaintiffs' attorneys are every bit as willing to point the finger. Insurance companies, they charge, are using deceptive tales of excessive damage awards to justify the exorbitant premiums that they charge the public. Says Browne Greene, president-elect of the California Trial Lawyers Association: "Their greed takes us back to the robber barons of the 19th century." Many consumer organizations add that insurers are seeking unjustified premium hikes to cover up their own bad management and poor judgment of risks.

Americans have always been a litigious people. But there does seem to be a rise in the number and size of liability suits facing every type of company, from soccer-ball makers to cigarette manufacturers. From 1977 to 1981, the number of civil lawsuits in state courts grew four times as fast as the population of the U.S. And in the decade between 1974 and 1984, the number of product-liability suits in federal courts expanded 680%. The first million-dollar verdict did not occur until 1962, but there were 401 in 1984, according to Jury Verdict Research Inc., a private group. The average verdict in product-liability cases now tops $1 million; preliminary figures for 1985 indicate that the average verdict in medical malpractice cases also exceeded $1 million for the first time. These giant awards, insurers say, exert an influence out of proportion to their numbers. They set a target for plaintiffs and their attorneys to shoot for, and move defendants to offer high out-of-court settlements rather than take a chance on what a jury might do.

The Association of Trial Lawyers of America counters by arguing that the Jury Verdict Research figures on averages are distorted by a relatively small number of huge verdicts. In addition, they say, the figures count only the initial outcomes of trials that the plaintiffs won. If defendant victories, out-of-court settlements and verdicts reduced on appeal were factored in, say the lawyers, even the average level of awards would be much lower. ATLA asserts that more than two-thirds of the million-dollar awards compensate victims or relatives for genuinely serious injuries, such as death or permanent paralysis, reflecting a laudable determination by juries to see that companies pay the price for misdeeds that once went unpunished.

In some cases, people are successfully pressing claims that seem patently silly. One example: a man who attempted suicide by jumping in front of a subway train sued the New York City Transit Authority, contending that the motorman of the subway that hit him had been negligently slow in bringing the train to a halt. He won $650,000 in an out-of-court settlement.

Yet much of the lore surrounding the subject has been exaggerated. ATLA analyzed several cases that insurers regularly trot out to prove that the system has got out of hand and found that the facts did not quite support the versions that have passed into insurance folklore and public print, although one or two, even after correction, still sound odd. Some examples:

According to one frequently cited tale, a body builder competing in a footrace with a refrigerator strapped to his back was injured when one of the straps came loose; he sued several defendants, including the strapmaker, and won $1 million. The facts, according to the lawyers' group: ten athletes competed in a televised stunt race, each with a 400-lb. refrigerator strapped to his back; each received a written contract guaranteeing that the equipment had been tested for safety. Franco Columbo, a world-champion body builder, did fall and suffered total knee displacement that required extensive surgery. At the trial, testimony showed that the equipment had never been tested on anyone of Columbo's size while running (he is 5 ft. 7 in., much smaller than anyone else in the race). In fact, the engineer for the fitness center that developed the contest said that he had warned the organizer, Trans World International, that the whole race was unsafe. Columbo did win slightly less than $1 million from Trans World, but the strapmaker was not sued because the strap never broke.

Another tale allegedly involves a fat man with a history of coronary disease who suffered a heart attack while trying to start a Sears lawn mower, sued Sears and the manufacturer, contending that too much force was required to pull the rope, and won $1,750,000. The real story, the trial lawyers point out, is that a 32-year-old doctor, who had no history of heart trouble, fell victim to a heart attack after futilely yanking the lawn mower's starter cord 15 times. A Philadelphia jury found that the mower's exhaust valve failed to meet the manufacturer's own specifications, hindering start-up to the extent that the rope indeed had to be pulled with excessive force. The jury did award $1,750,000, but the case was subsequently settled for an undisclosed amount.

Another oft-used example is of two Maryland men who supposedly put a hot-air balloon into a commercial laundry dryer. The machine exploded, injuring both men, who won $885,000 from the maker of the dryer. What actually happened is that the men took the balloon to a hospital that had laundry equipment designed for industrial purposes. The dryer vibrated violently and then exploded. Both men were injured; one required microsurgery to reattach his hand, which was almost severed. The dryer's maker had a patent on a device that would have stopped the dryer automatically if it began to vibrate excessively, but had declined to install the device on the dryer because of the cost. Oddly, in this case the actual award, $1,260,000, exceeded the figure usually quoted, but the lawyers point out that the common account of the case ignores the dryer manufacturer's failure to install the protective device.

In yet another celebrated case, a burglar supposedly fell through the skylight of a school, sued and was awarded $260,000, plus $1,500 a month. The full story, it seems, is that a 19-year-old man and three friends tried to take a floodlight off the roof of a California high school as a lark; he fell through the skylight and suffered loss of the use of all four limbs, plus severe brain damage. The skylight had been painted the same color as the roof and was indistinguishable at night; the school district knew that it was dangerous because someone else had been killed falling through a similar skylight at another school six months earlier, and had scheduled the skylight for repainting. It settled out of court for $260,000, plus $1,200 a month initially, to be increased by 3% each year. Still, it seems debatable whether someone should be so generously compensated for injuries, even that severe, sustained while committing a theft.

Yet whatever the merits of these and other specific cases, the insurance companies are correct in their basic contention: an evolution in liability law has led to higher jury awards and is at least partly responsible for the rise in insurance rates. One important change: the amounts assessed by juries to compensate for lost wages, medical payments and the like now make up a small part of many liability awards. Juries are increasingly likely to add on far larger amounts for noneconomic damages, that is, for such unquantifiable things as pain and suffering.

Equally significant is the growing size of punitive damages, which supposedly serve the same purpose as a don't-ever-do-anything-like-that-again fine of the defendant. Juries sometimes find that a person's actual damages amounted to only a few thousand dollars, yet decide that the corporation at fault should also pay punitive damages in the millions. In one startling case, now awaiting decision by the U.S. Supreme Court, an Alabama couple sued Aetna Life & Casualty Co., claiming that it had wrongfully refused to pay $1,650 of the wife's hospital bill. A jury awarded them punitive damages of $3.5 million, or 2,121 times the size of the disputed bill.

Courts and legislatures have steadily expanded definitions of who can be sued, and on what grounds. These days you usually can sue city hall, despite the doctrine of sovereign immunity, which holds that governments cannot be sued without their consent. State laws, and court interpretations of them, have granted that consent more and more.

Another legal concept being used ever more widely is that of strict liability, which makes possible an award of damages without any proof of negligence. Initially it was applied, for example, to businesses conducting abnormally dangerous activities. Now it has been expanded to product-liability cases: a plaintiff need not prove that the manufacturer of a product was negligent, only that the plaintiff was injured while using the product in the manner intended.

More states have also adopted looser standards of comparative negligence. Even if an accident was partly due to the plaintiffs own negligence, he can successfully sue someone else who also bears some of the blame. In California, for example, a woman who stumbled in a church parking lot on the way to a meeting sued the church, the group holding the meeting and the city, contending that the lot was not lit well enough. Although the defendants felt she was largely responsible, all three agreed to a settlement paying her $80,000.

Perhaps the thorniest concept, one that has become a growing factor in many cases, is called "joint and several liability." It allows a plaintiff to sue everyone who might share in the responsibility for an accident, and if any one of the defendants is found to be partially at fault, that defendant may be forced to pay the entire judgment. Originally, it was applied to wrongdoers who had acted in concert, but now is more often invoked against defendants who acted independently. In practice, it increasingly means that awards fall most heavily on the defendant with "deep pockets," often the one carrying the most insurance. The doctrine is now in force in nearly all states.

One way to show how these concepts work--and the effects they can have on insurance coverage--is through a classic case settled last year that began with a child's fall and ended with most of Chicago's parks being stripped of certain kinds of playground equipment. It began in 1978 when two-year-old Frank Nelson fell through a wide space at the top of a slide in a city playground and struck his head on the pavement 11 ft. below. He suffered severe brain damage; the left side of his body is still paralyzed, and his speech and vision are impaired. Nelson's family sued the manufacturer of the slide, the contractor who installed it and the Chicago Park District. Lawyers contended that the district had been negligent in failing to warn against use of the slide by small children, in not providing proper supervision of the playground and not putting a softer surface under the slide.

Officials of the park district and its insurer, U.S. Fidelity and Guaranty Co. of Baltimore, still contend that the primary responsibility for the accident fell on Frank's mother; she allowed the boy to go on a slide he was too young to use, and should have been watching him more closely. But they never formally accused the mother of negligence in pretrial proceedings; such an argument would not have succeeded unless they also could have convinced a jury that the park district bore no blame whatever. In this case the park district was the defendant with the deep pockets--$50 million in liability insurance--and Fidelity was afraid that it would be hit with the largest share of any judgment. Paul Jacob, the insurer's Chicago branch manager, notes that in Illinois a defendant who is found to bear any part of the responsibility for an accident can be liable for all of a damage award. Says he: "Showing that any defendant is not 1% negligent is virtually impossible."

Unwilling to risk paying the damages a jury might award to a child who had been so severely injured, Fidelity offered a settlement. It proposed to put up $1.5 million to buy an annuity that will make payments each year to Frank Nelson for the rest of his life. The family accepted, and the case was closed without trial.

But that is not quite the end of the story. Fidelity at first canceled the park district's insurance, but eventually renewed for much less coverage at a greatly increased premium. "Park districts are a terrible risk for any carrier to have to assume," explains Jacob. Finally, the park district, gun-shy because several suits are still pending against it, began tearing down all jungle gyms and slides over 6 1/2 ft. high and carting them out of the city's 513 playgrounds. "Accidents happen no matter what you do," says Park District Treasurer Jack Matthews. "In the past, when Johnny fell off the swings, the park superintendent took him to the hospital, and that was the end of it. Now the parks are inundated with suits."

Such cases show how complex and changing legal doctrines can increase the risks faced by insurance companies and make those risks more unpredictable. But, as consumer advocates point out, they do not explain the full story. The legal doctrines in question have been evolving for many years. The rise in the number of personal-injury lawsuits and the size of jury awards has also been gradual. But apart from medical malpractice insurance, which has been a headache for both doctors and insurers for at least a decade, it is only in the past two years that liability premiums have exploded and policies have been canceled wholesale.

What happened? Lawyers and consumer activists charge that insurers are paying the price--or, rather, trying to make the public pay the price--for their own mismanagement and bad judgment. Liability insurance has always been a notoriously cyclical industry. Says Robert Hunter, head of the National Insurance Consumer Organization: "At the top of the cycle you write [policies for] everybody, no matter how bad, and at the bottom you cancel everybody, no matter how good. It's a manic-depressive cycle."

Harsh words, but again containing some truth. In the best of times, property and casualty insurers, the kind that issue liability policies, rarely make much money on underwriting: the premiums collected have exceeded claims paid in only two of the past ten years. Most of their profits come from investing the premiums they collect. Five years ago, when the prime rate, keystone of the U.S. interest-rate structure, hit an incredible high of 21 1/2%, such investments paid off very, very well.

Insurers grudgingly concede that they went all out to attract premium income that could be invested at those towering interest rates. They wrote liability policies that posed a high risk at premiums low enough to almost guarantee an underwriting loss; competitive rate-cutting slashed some premiums by 20% or more. But the insurers never got the bonanza they expected. Underwriting losses rose faster than investment income grew even when interest rates were at their peak.

Then the bottom fell out. Interest rates began tumbling in 1981; the prime is now at an eight-year low of 9%. Underwriting losses ballooned. Foreign reinsurers--Lloyd's of London is the biggest--that indemnify most American casualty companies against extraordinary losses, cut back sharply or ran away from the business entirely, leaving the American firms to shoulder the losses alone. Finally, in 1984 underwriting losses swallowed up investment income entirely and, according to industry statistics, property-casualty insurers suffered an overall pretax loss of $3.8 billion. It was the first red-ink figure in nine years. In 1985 the pretax loss increased to $5.5 billion. Some 40 liability insurers have become insolvent in the past two years.

Like the figures on jury verdicts, the insurers' profit-and-loss statistics are in sharp dispute. Consumer advocates insist that if adjustments are made for some quirks in insurance accounting (primarily involving the treatment of taxes, dividends and the rising paper value of investments), the industry made a net profit every year. The Insurance Information Institute, indeed, has acknowledged an industry profit after taxes of $1.7 billion last year, which it contends still amounts to a poor return.

The National Insurance Consumer Organization maintains that the true figure was $5 billion. Given that, the industry's critics argue, the premium increases now being posted go far beyond what is justified. Sneers Gerry Spence, a famed Wyoming trial lawyer (no relation to Miami's J.B. Spence): "What the insurance companies have done is to reverse the business so that the public at large insures the insurance companies." Consumerists often point to the judgment of Wall Street, hardly a Naderite stronghold. Stock traders bid up the price of property-casualty insurance shares an average of about 50% last year, in the apparent belief that the industry at minimum is on its way back to solid profitability.

Well, maybe. But that road to recovery threatens, at least for the moment, to cripple large segments of the U.S. economy and be extremely costly for every policyholder, taxpayer and consumer. Every day brings word of new repercussions: doctors raising their fees, playgrounds closing, swimming meets being called off, transit systems facing financial jolts, fraternities having their coverage canceled, oil-field service companies closing down. Amid all of the attendant finger pointing, a serious search is under way for some solutions.

Self-insurance is a strategy that many businesses, professional people and governments are exploring (or, more often, being forced into). But the experience of doctors indicates it is not much of a solution. In the mid-1970s, doctors organized a number of companies, promptly dubbed "bedpan mutuals," to write malpractice insurance at lower premiums. But several of the bedpan mutuals are said to be in financial trouble, and as a group they too are raising premiums rapidly. Going bare is an act of desperation: business executives and professionals who are operating without insurance almost unanimously voice deep worry that a single big lawsuit could wipe them out.

As might be expected, many are seeking new legislation as a solution. But what line should it take? One approach is called tort reform, which involves putting limits on damage awards in malpractice, negligence and personal-injury cases. Advocates insist that this will allow insurers to get enough of a handle on their potential risks to make writing liability policies a predictable exercise rather than a crapshoot. The leading ideas:

Put limits on pain-and-suffering awards and punitive damages. Republican Senator Mitch McConnell of Kentucky has introduced a congressional bill encouraging states to cap pain-and-suffering awards at $100,000 and to require that punitive damages be paid to a court, as outright fines are, rather than to a plaintiff and his or her attorney.

Establish stricter standards for proving who really bears how much of the blame for an accident or injury. Senator John Danforth, a Missouri Republican, is sponsoring a bill that would set uniform federal standards in product-liability cases to replace the present morass of 50 often conflicting state laws; it would require a plaintiff to prove negligence or fault by the manufacturer.

Either abolish the doctrine of joint and several liability or revise it along the lines of a proposition that Californians will put to a vote on June 3. The proposition would make a defendant's share of any pain-and-suffering award proportionate to the defendant's degree of blame; a defendant found to bear 25%, say, of the responsibility for an accident or injury could be forced to pay no more than 25% of the damages. That would be more equitable, but requiring juries to assess proportionate shares of fault among several defendants would add to the complexity of lawsuits and the time needed to settle them.

Limit contingency fees, so that lawyers would have less incentive to seek outsize damages for their clients. Several states are pondering variations on a California law that sets up a sliding scale in medical malpractice cases: an attorney can take up to 40% of the first $50,000 of a judgment, but that share dwindles by stages to only 10% of any amount over $200,000.

Institute some sort of punishment, perhaps a fine, for attorneys who file frivolous suits. At minimum, reformers often urge adoption of the European system, under which the loser of a lawsuit usually pays the winner's court costs.

This last idea has yet to gain much ground, but different combinations of the others are being advanced in several states. The National Conference of State Legislatures estimates that around 1,200 bills have been introduced since last December dealing with the insurance crisis in one way or another, and most contain some sort of tort reform. On the federal level, besides the McConnell and Danforth proposals, a Reagan Administration study group headed by Assistant Attorney General Richard Willard is expected to recommend a bill limiting pain-and-suffering awards and punitive damages; it would also establish tighter standards for gauging fault to govern suits in federal courts. (Uncle Sam has more than a bystander's interest: the U.S. was a defendant in more than 10,000 damage suits in fiscal 1985, and wound up paying $200 million to plaintiffs.)

Some 600 members of the National Association of Manufacturers descended on Washington last week to lobby for the Danforth bill, which besides setting national standards for product-liability suits would establish a new procedure for speedy out-of-court settlement of claims for economic damages. They first gathered at the Marriott Hotel to swap horror stories and pep talks. Under present legal rules, "you're afraid to try anything, put any new product on the market," cried Gust Headbloom, president of Michigan's Apex Broach & Machinery Co. Peter J. Nord, president of Schauer Manufacturing Corp. in Cincinnati, which makes battery-charging machines, drew loud applause by declaring, "There are going to be people who are dumb and stupid and screw up no matter what we do." Ohio Democratic Congressman Thomas Luken showed up to cheer on the manufacturers. Said he: "Probably no recent issue has snowballed so quickly."

After eating paper-bag lunches, the manufacturers boarded buses to Capitol Hill to buttonhole legislators from their home states. So many Michiganders packed into the office of Democratic Senator Carl Levin that several of the businessmen had to perch on upended attache cases. Levin warned them that "the whole spirit of Congress is to get away from regulation," but promised to take a careful look at the Danforth bill. Plaintiffs' attorneys, needless to say, oppose all tort-reform plans. They commonly accuse insurers of creating a sense of crisis to enact laws that would deny just compensation to victims of malpractice or injury. More troubling, they insist that all the tort-reform ideas would undermine a fundamental principle of democracy: the idea that any citizen should have unrestricted access to the courts for redress of any grievances he might suffer. Robert Habush, president of the Association of Trial Lawyers, says of the tort-reform movement, "In my 25 years in law, this is as serious a threat to the civil justice system as I have ever seen. People have decided there is going to be a hanging, and it is just a question of what tree and what rope."

In all probability, that seriously overstates the case. Present and former trial lawyers populate state legislatures and Congress in numbers large enough to wield formidable blocking power. There is a question, too, of whether the courts would uphold any serious tort reforms that might be enacted. One omen: the Cook County, Ill., circuit court last year ruled that major parts of a newly enacted law stretching out damage awards in medical malpractice cases violated the Illinois constitution.

The alternative legislative approach to the insurance crisis is tighter regulation of insurance companies. At the federal level, trial lawyers and consumer advocates are pressing for repeal of the insurance industry's exemption from antitrust laws. That exemption allows insurers to share information and, according to their opponents, engage in collusive premium-setting policies that would be illegal in any other industry. In state legislatures, many proposed bills would enlarge the authority of insurance commissioners to block arbitrary policy cancellations and gargantuan premium increases. The Florida department of insurance has written a proposed bill that would require insurers to disclose what discounts and surcharges they apply to premium rates. Without that information, says Insurance Commissioner Bill Gunter, "the rate itself is meaningless." He adds, "We think insurers need someone to look over their shoulder and keep them honest."

One mildly encouraging sign is that a growing number of legislators seem to recognize that, just as the crisis has no single cause, it cannot have any single solution. They are proposing various combinations of tighter insurance regulation and tort reform. A bill on the verge of enactment by the Minnesota legislature would set up "joint underwriting associations" to issue liability policies, written by the state, to customers who could not get commercial insurance; any losses would be picked up jointly by the state's insurers. But to limit those losses, the bill also would restrict punitive damages, among other tort reforms.

Some combination of measures seems needed, and fast. Anything that affects matters ranging from the pace of oil exploration to the availability of slides in Chicago playgrounds must be taken very seriously. The nation, once proud of its frontier individualism, has gradually adopted a no-risk mentality based on the belief that if anything bad happens, someone should be made to pay. But as damage awards lose any connection to actual damages and insurance companies flail around anxiously, that someone is turning out to be everyone. --By George J. Church. Reported by Anne Constable/Washington, B. Russell Leavitt/Atlanta and Michael Riley/Los Angeles

With reporting by Anne Constable/Washington, B. Russell Leavitt/Atlanta, Michael Riley/Los Angeles